CONGRESSIONAL RECORD - SENATE
AUGUST 30. 1962
PAGE 18243
THE TRADE EXPANSION ACT
Mr. MUSKIE. Mr. President, the Senate Committee on Finance is nearing the close of its
deliberations on the Trade Expansion Act of 1962. Shortly we will be called upon to cast our
votes on this vital legislation.
Three weeks ago, I introduced an amendment to H.R. 11970, which has been referred to the
Finance Committee. Subsequently I testified before the committee in support of that amendment.
Because I believe this amendment is of general interest and importance to my colleagues, I ask
unanimous consent that the text of my testimony be printed in the RECORD at this point.
There being no objection, the statement was ordered to be printed in the RECORD, as follows:
STATEMENT BY U.S. SENATOR EDMUND S. MUSKIE, OF MAINE, IN SUPPORT OF
HIS AMENDMENT TO H.R. 11970, THE TRADE EXPANSION ACT OF 1962, BEFORE
THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE, AUGUST 14, 1962
Mr. Chairman, first may I express my appreciation to you and the members of this committee for
giving me an opportunity to appear before you at this time. I know your sessions have been long
and grueling, and I recognize that you still have the hard job of drafting and reporting this
important legislation. I hope my testimony will provide a constructive contribution to your
deliberations.
My comments will be brief, and to the point. At the conclusion of my testimony I shall be
pleased to answer any questions you may wish to direct to me.
On Thursday, August 2, 1 introduced an amendment to H.R. 11970, the Trade Expansion Act of
1962, which would give the President specific authority to enter into orderly marketing
agreements with foreign countries, where such agreements would serve to protect domestic
manufacturers from disastrous increases in imports from foreign industries producing articles
under substandard wages and working conditions.
This proposal, in my opinion, is consistent with the objectives of the President's program for
expanded trade; it is in line with his "adjustment assistance" program for workers and industries
injured as a result of our trade policies; and it would provide meaningful protection for a
substantial group of industries confronted with low-wage competition from highly industrialized
and efficient operations overseas. At the same time, it would not shut the door to foreign trade,
but would assure foreign manufacturers an opportunity to share in the orderly growth in our
domestic market. It would provide a tool for the President to use, in those cases where the tool is
practicable, in halting market chaos and in giving domestic manufacturers a "breathing space" in
which to adjust to changing competitive conditions.
I have been pleased by the bipartisan support this proposal has received, including the
cosponsorship of Senators BARTLETT, of Alaska, CHAVEZ, of New Mexico, COTTON and
MURPHY, of New Hampshire, DODD, of Connecticut, PASTORE and PELL, of Rhode Island,
WILEY, of Wisconsin, LONG of Missouri, and RANDOLPH, of West Virginia. Other
distinguished Senators, on both sides of the aisle, have indicated their willingness to vote for the
amendment. I hope this committee will adopt the proposal as a part of its recommendation to the
Senate.
In speaking to you, today, I want to stress the fact that I believe very firmly in the importance of
trade, not only as a factor in the maintenance of the free world economy, but also as a vital
ingredient in our own development and growth. I recognize, however, as the President has done,
that trade cannot be expanded without some dislocation -- some injury, if you will -- to certain
segments of domestic industry.
My recommendations can be considered in two parts. The first is an examination of the special
problems of low-wage competition, and the second is the specific remedy which I propose as an
addition to those already specifically provided to the President.
The essence of the free trade argument is that competition is good for everyone. It encourages
efficiency, economical allocation of resources, better quality, and lower prices. These are the
ingredients of the free enterprise system in our domestic economy. What is often overlooked is
the fact that the free enterprise system succeeds only where one has a more or less homogeneous
community, where there is mobility of capital and labor, and where certain minimum standards
are maintained with respect to wages and working conditions, trade practices, and so forth.
The Fair Labor Standards Act is first and foremost a humanitarian document, designed to insure
a decent standard of living for each person willing and able to work. It is also a device for
protecting employers who pay their workers decent wages from unfair competition by those who
pay substandard wages and impose poor working conditions on their employees.
In the arena of international trade we cannot impose an international fair labor standards law. But
we can recognize that the problem of wage cost differentials does exist.
The European Common Market has recognized this factor, and has taken steps to minimize the
problems it creates, as did the earlier Benelux Economic Union, formed by Belgium,
Luxembourg, and the Netherlands.
In creating the Benelux Union difficulties were encountered in reconciling the economies of
Belgium and the Netherlands. In many instances, wages in the Netherlands were considerably
lower than wages in Belgium and, in consequence, money costs of production in the Netherlands
tended to be lower than costs in Belgium.
The agreement of July 1953, establishing the Benelux Union, recognized these differences, and
measures were adopted to raise the general level of wages in the Netherlands. At the time, this
was not too difficult because of the favorable balance-of-payments position of the Netherlands.
Under articles 48-51 of the December 1957 Treaty of Rome, establishing the European Economic
Community, it is provided that all restrictions on the movement of labor, capital and enterprises
within the Community are to be abolished by the end of the transition period, together with the
gradual abolition of tariffs and other restrictions on commerce among the member states. All
discrimination based on nationality regarding employment, wages, and other working conditions
is to be eliminated.
The Treaty of Rome recognizes that it will not be easy to allow labor, and capital, particularly
labor, to move freely among the member states. Accordingly, it provides for a European social
fund that is intended to improve the possibilities of employment and to increase the geographic
and occupational mobility of labor within the Community.
Thus, there is precedent for recognizing that commerce between countries with widely disparate
levels of living presents problems of adjustment that cannot be solved overnight. The idea of
adjustment assistance through the social fund is an attempt by the member states to work with,
rather than against, the forces of economic adjustment.
This is the underlying argument for the adjustment assistance provisions of H.R. 11970. It is also
an argument for additional tools in the control of the pattern of trade to help us work with those
forces which will encourage a healthy growth in trade patterns.
I recognize that differences in wage rates, by themselves, do not constitute an adequate yardstick
for judging the degree of competitiveness between U.S. producers of a given product and their
foreign competitors. To be meaningful, wages must be related to the productivity of labor and to
other costs of production, including the cost of raw materials. Highly paid labor that is highly
productive is low-cost labor, in terms of the unit of product, as compared with low-paid labor
that is relatively unproductive. The test of unfairness of competition is whether the labor
involved receives wages and fringe benefits, per unit of output, that are substantially lower than
wages and fringe benefits received for comparable labor in this country.
There can be little doubt that a country in which wages are generally low, relative to labor's
productivity, is enabled to compete abroad in certain lines of production in which it would not be
able to compete in the absence of this advantage. Competition of this kind is particularly
troublesome in lines of production in which it is relatively easy to transfer from one product line
to another. Soft consumer goods, such as textiles and shoes, are particularly vulnerable. Other
industries facing comparable problems include electronics components and the wood-turning
industries.
On August 2, this committee heard testimony by Mr. Harold Toor, treasurer of the National Shoe
Manufacturers Association, illustrating the problem which arises when an efficient, highly
competitive domestic industry is hit by efficient, highly competitive imports from countries
where labor output is high and wages are low.
Imports of footwear, leather and nonleather types, have increased 234.5 percent since 1957 --
from 11 million pairs in 1957 to 36.8 million pairs in 1961. For the first 6 months of 1962 they
have more than doubled the rate of the comparable period of 1 year ago. They were 6.1 percent of
domestic production in 1961, 10.3 percent of domestic production in the first half of 1962, and
15.4 percent of domestic production in June 1962. While imports have been increasing, our exports have dropped from 4.4 million pairs in 1957 to 3 million pairs in 1961.
The impact of such competition must be measured not only in terms of the volume of imports,
but also in the rate of expansion and the ability of the foreign competitor to concentrate on
certain lines of production and to shift rapidly from one line to another. The key to the problem is
market disruption.
Tariffs do not provide an adequate answer to this problem, since the difference in foreign and
domestic costs allows foreign exporters to land their product in the United States at 15 percent to
26 percent less than the price of the domestic product. Some other technique must be found to
slow down this disruptive change if we are to protect the jobs of the 350,000 to 400,000 workers
in the 1,300 factories in 650 communities in 38 of our States.
Another technique is available, and has been used by this administration in the case of the
Geneva textile agreements. This is the technique of orderly marketing agreements. Such
agreements offer to domestic manufacturers the assurance that their markets will not be taken
away from them suddenly, in a situation where they cannot possibly compete. At the same time,
the arrangements for such restrictions on imports as are necessary are carried out in a spirit of
cooperation between the exporting country and this Nation. Foreign exporters are told that they
will not be shut out of the domestic market, but that they will have an opportunity to share in the
American market as it grows. They will be given the chance to compete for a fair share of that
market.
Last year, I introduced S.1735, the Orderly Marketing Act of 1961. This legislation spelled out
the procedures and the formula which would be applicable in the establishment of orderly
marketing agreements. My amendment, which I advocate today, carries out the intent of S. 1735,
within the framework of the general trade bill.
Under the amendment the President is given the specific authority to enter into orderly marketing
agreements with other countries, to arrange for such import restrictions as are necessary to
protect domestic industries struggling against a sudden flood of low-wage imports. Such
authority is not contained in the legislation, as written. I believe it should be included.
The amendment does not tie the President's hands. It does not say that this is the only technique
of adjustment assistance or trade protection. It says only that this is one useful device, the merit
of which the President has recognized, which should be available to him in his implementation of
our trade policy.
I urge the members of this committee to include this proposal in the Trade Expansion Act.